Droop quota

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

In the study of electoral systems, the Droop quota (sometimes called the Hagenbach-Bischoff, Britton, or Newland-Britton quota[1][a]) is the minimum number of votes needed for a party or candidate to guarantee a full seat in a legislature.[2]

The Droop quota generalizes the concept of a majority to multiwinner elections. Just as a candidate with a majority (more than half of all votes) is guaranteed to be declared winner in a one-on-one election, a candidate who holds more than one Droop quota's worth of votes at any point is guaranteed to win a seat in a multiwinner election.[b]

Besides establishing winners, the Droop quota is used to define the number of excess votes, votes not needed by a candidate who has been declared elected. In proportional quota-rule systems such as STV and CPO-STV, these excess votes can be transferred to other candidates, preventing them from being wasted.

The Droop quota was first devised by the English lawyer and mathematician Henry Richmond Droop (1831–1884), as an alternative to the Hare quota. Hagenbach-Bischoff also wrote on the quota in 1888, in his study entitled Die Frage der Einführung einer Proportionalvertretung statt des absoluten Mehres.

Today, the Droop quota is used in almost all STV elections, including those in the Republic of Ireland, Northern Ireland, Malta, and Australia.[citation needed] It is also used in South Africa to allocate seats by the largest remainder method.[citation needed]

Standard Formula[edit]

The exact form of the Droop quota for a -winner election is given by the expression:[1][3]

In the case of a single-winner election, this reduces to the familiar simple majority rule. Under such a rule, a candidate can be declared elected as soon as they have strictly more than 50% of the vote, i.e. .[1]

Sometimes, the Droop quota is written as a share (i.e. percentage) of the total votes, in which case it has value 1k+1. A candidate holding strictly more than one full Droop quota's worth of votes is guaranteed to win a seat. Sometimes the quota is described as , with being taken arbitrarily small, allowing the word "strictly" to be dropped from the above definition.

Derivation[edit]

The Droop quota can be derived by considering what would happen if k candidates (called "Droop winners") have exceeded the Droop quota; the goal is to identify whether an outside candidate could defeat any of these candidates.

In this situation, each quota winner's share of the vote exceeds 1k+1, while all unelected candidates' share of the vote, taken together, is less than 1k+1 votes. Thus, even if there were only one unelected candidate who held all the remaining votes, they would not be able to defeat any of the Droop winners.

Example in STV[edit]

The following election has 3 seats to be filled by single transferable vote. There are 4 candidates: George Washington, Alexander Hamilton, Thomas Jefferson, and Aaron Burr. There are 102 voters, but two of the votes are spoiled.

The total number of valid votes is 100, and there are 3 seats. The Droop quota is therefore . These votes are as follows:

45 voters 20 voters 25 voters 10 voters
1 Washington Burr Jefferson Hamilton
2 Hamilton Jefferson Burr Washington
3 Jefferson Washington Washington Jefferson

First preferences for each candidate are tallied:

  • Washington: 45 checkY
  • Hamilton: 10
  • Burr: 20
  • Jefferson: 25

Only Washington has strictly more than 25 votes. As a result, he is immediately elected. Washington has 20 excess votes that can be transferred to their second choice, Hamilton. The tallies therefore become:

  • Washington: 25 checkY
  • Hamilton: 30checkY
  • Burr: 20
  • Jefferson: 25

Hamilton is elected, so his excess votes are redistributed. Thanks to Hamilton's support, Jefferson receives 30 votes to Burr's 20 and is elected.

If all of Hamilton's supporters had instead backed Burr, the election for the last seat would have been exactly tied, instead of a clear win for Jefferson, requiring a tiebreaker.

Common errors[edit]

There is a great deal of confusion among legislators and political observers about the exact form of the Droop quota.[4] At least six different versions appear in various legal codes or definitions of the quota, all varying by one vote.[4] Such versions have been discouraged by the ERS handbook since 1976.[1] Common variants include:

The first two variants arise from Droop's work, which assumed a whole number of votes would be transferred at random;[1] the error in this procedure could be reduced by duplicating each voter's ballot times, allowing any error to cancel. As a result, Droop described his quota as "the whole number next greater than the quotient obtained by dividing , the number of votes, by ."[4] With large, this corresponds to the exact form of the quota including , while for (no duplication) it would correspond to the rounded quota.

The middle two variants are rarely-used and exist as a result of transcription or communication errors. They are still admissible quotas, i.e. they will never assign too many or too few seats. The last two variants are simply too small and as such can apportion more seats than actually exist.[4]

Spoiled ballots should not be included when calculating the Droop quota. However, some jurisdictions fail to specify this in their election administration laws.[citation needed]

Confusion with the Hare quota[edit]

The Droop quota is often confused with the more intuitive Hare quota. While the Droop quota gives the number of voters needed to mathematically guarantee a candidate's election, the Hare quota gives the number of voters who are represented by each winner in an ideally-proportional system, i.e. one where every voter is represented equally.

The confusion between the two quotas originates from a fencepost error, caused by forgetting that unelected candidates can also have votes at the end of the counting process. In the case of a single-winner election, using the Hare quota would lead to the incorrect conclusion that a candidate must receive 100% of the vote to be certain of victory; in reality, any votes exceeding a bare majority are excess votes.

The Droop quota is today the most popular quota for STV elections.[citation needed]

See also[edit]

Notes[edit]

  1. ^ Some authors use the terms "Newland-Britton quota" or "exact Droop quota" to refer to the quantity described in this article, and reserve the term "Droop quota" for the rounded Droop quota (the original form in the works of Henry Droop).
  2. ^ See #Derivation for why this is true regardless of the quota used for transfers.

References[edit]

  1. ^ a b c d e Lundell, Jonathan; Hill, ID (October 2007). "Notes on the Droop quota" (PDF). Voting Matters (24): 3–6.
  2. ^ "Droop Quota", The Encyclopedia of Political Science, 2300 N Street, NW, Suite 800, Washington DC 20037 United States: CQ Press, 2011, doi:10.4135/9781608712434.n455, ISBN 978-1-933116-44-0, retrieved 2024-05-03{{citation}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  3. ^ Woodall, Douglass. "Properties of Preferential Election Rules". Voting matters (3).
  4. ^ a b c d Dančišin, Vladimír (2013). "Misinterpretation of the Hagenbach-Bischoff quota". Annales Scientia Politica. 2 (1): 76.

Sources[edit]

  • Robert, Henry M.; et al. (2011). Robert's Rules of Order Newly Revised (11th ed.). Philadelphia, Pennsylvania: Da Capo Press. p. 4. ISBN 978-0-306-82020-5.

Further reading[edit]